ANTICIPATED VALUE IN EXPROPRIATION COMPENSATION CLAIMS OF RESOURCE PROPERTIES Normally, conventional appraisal principles require that aggregate resource property be valued on a discounted cash flow basis.1 There are a number of issues that arise, however, when the government or other authority expropriates a resource property, especially one containing resources that find their way into the work or project giving rise to the expropriation. First, there is a statutory prohibition under most current Canadian legal regimes against the landowner being compensated the so-called "anticipated value". This restriction is in fact a creature of expropriation law and is not part of conventional appraisal or valuation principles. Its scope and meaning are matters of judicial interpretation by the courts. The Nova Scotia statutory provision is typical of other jurisdictions. It provides:
Second, there may be inequity in that the expropriated owner may not be able to benefit from anticipated value, while his unexpropriated neighbour may do so. The authority must pay full current market price to the unexpropriated owner (subject, perhaps, to a volume discount) while the expropriated owner is offered, at most, the value of his property on a discounted cash flow basis for aggregate that is to be consumed immediately in the project. "It is well settled that compensation for the compulsory acquisition of land cannot include an increase in value which is entirely due to the scheme underlying the acquisition." Notwithstanding this legislative and judicial restriction, the cases indicate that the courts will not allow governments to do by compulsory acquisition what they could not do privately, i.e., gain access to valuable resources on less than fair terms. Essentially, the methodology used by the courts is to consider what the government would do, absent expropriation powers, if it had to go into the market-place to acquire the resource for the construction of the government project. For this purpose, it does not matter that the government is a special purchaser, a principal purchaser or even the sole purchaser in the market-place.5 "By giving cabinet approval to the plan to construct a causeway, the Crown made it known that there was a probable rather than a possible market for the appellant's rock at the price which a willing purchaser would pay to a willing vendor..." Further, the Court said: "If the special adaptability of the lands is to be measured in terms of the value of the rock in situ, the quantity involved must, in my opinion, be treated as being the amount of the requirement estimated by the Crown before expropriation...this constituted an immediate market for a substantial amount of the appellant's rock and the unprecedented opportunity to dispose of such a quantity of his supply at one time must, in my view, be treated as a circumstance which would induce a prudent man to willingly accept less than he might expect to receive if he was required to sell the commodity piecemeal, with all respect, it does not, in my opinion, mean that such a man should be required to accept less than one-tenth of the amount which an experienced contractor would have been prepared to pay if he had to include the rock in his tender for the contract, and this appears to me to be the effect of the value fixed by the learned trial judge." In Fraser, the Court was dealing with the valuation of the potential use created by an expropriating authority when the Federal Crown decided to build a causeway over the Strait of Canso. It expropriated a piece of land with 9 million tonnes of rock, which was intended to be used to construct the causeway. The Crown was trying to expropriate the land for $50.00 per acre. There was evidence from a contractor who offered $450,000.00 for a comparable amount of rock. The Court concluded that land was being taken from the Appellant, not to be used as land, but as a source of building material for which there was an ascertainable market price. In the majority decision, the Supreme Court posed the following question: "Why, it may be asked, should a citizen who happens to own material suitable for use in the building of a public work and in a most convenient location, but of which there are ample available supplies in the hands of other owners, be required to make a gift of his property?" In fixing compensation, the Court said it must not reflect in any way the value the property will have to the acquiring authority after expropriation and as an integral part of the scheme devised by that authority. Nevertheless, the Court concluded the Appellant was entitled to [the] then current price for the quantity of rock taken from the expropriated land. "For these reasons, Their Lordships have come to the conclusion, even where the only possible purchaser of the lands' potentiality is the authority that has obtained the compulsory powers, the arbitrator in awarding compensation must ascertain to the best of his ability the price that would be paid by a willing purchaser to a willing vendor of the land with its potentiality in the same way that he would ascertain it in a case where there are several possible purchasers...". With respect to anticipated value, the Court also said: "It must, of course, be conceded that the existence of the scheme must not be allowed to enhance the price, if by 'scheme' is meant the fact that compulsory powers of acquisition have been obtained for the purpose of carrying into effect a particular scheme for the profitable use of the potentiality. The valuation must always be made as though such powers have been acquired, and the only use that can be made of the scheme is as evidence that the acquiring authority can properly be regarded as possible purchasers." As the cases show, the compensation payable is not necessarily the market value of the whole of the aggregate obtainable. It is the market value of the aggregate required in the project. In Friesen v. Saskatchewan (1968), D.L.R. (2d) 171, the owner argued that the amount of compensation payable in the expropriation of a quarry or gravel pit was the fair market price for the quantity of material capable of being taken from the expropriated land. The Saskatchewan Court of Appeal rejected this contention and said: "The determination of the value of the land by reference to the market value of the rock in situ, required for the construction of the causeway was probably the only practical method of valuation under the particular circumstances there prevailing. Certainly, in my respectful opinion, the judgement of the Supreme Court [in Fraser] cannot be construed as establishing the principle that when the property expropriated is a quarry or gravel pit, the value to the owner is the market value of all the commodity attainable therefrom at the time of expropriation. Compensation so fixed would reflect the total potential value which the property will have to the expropriating authority after expropriation. It is clear from the judgement of Ritchie, J. (in Fraser), and from the authorities to which the learned judge refers, that the amount fixed by way of compensation must not in any way reflect the value which the property will have to the acquiring authority." In Golby v. Nova Scotia (1979), 34 N.S.R. (2d) 300, a post-modern Nova Scotia case which considered Section 33 of the Nova Scotia Act, the land fronted on an ice-free harbour of exceptional depth. The Nova Scotia Expropriations Compensation Board said: "It must be said that the Board has great difficulty in giving a strict application to the section in the peculiar circumstances of these cases because of the nature of the background anticipation which reduced the matter of eventual industrial and commercial use to a mere question of time." In short, the imminence of the governmental project can itself influence the market value of the resource. "The Board was advised that Section 14(4)(a) and (b) completely prohibited the consideration by the Board of Metro's use of lands as a garbage disposal site. The "special" use to which the authority has put the land is obviously such use. It would appear that this prohibition is not absolute. E.C.E. Todd in The Law of Expropriation and Compensation in Canada (1976), at p. 129, states: 'However, it should not be assumed that the scheme is to be disregarded completely in the determination of compensation. On the contrary, there are three different situations in which the scheme may be relevant ... (c) in considering special adaptability or potential.' The circumstances in this case are somewhat unique in that the "special" use for which the land was taken is the same use for which the owners acquired the land, and to which it would have been put if expropriation had not taken place. See also St. Catharines Crushed Stone Limited v. City of St. Catharines (1978), 15 L.C.R. 363. Prior to the publication of the expropriation, the purchaser cancelled an agreement of purchase and sale. The Ontario Land Compensation Board considered the purchase price in the agreement as an important and valid indication of the value on the property. The Board also looked at market value in terms of valuation based on the use for which the authority expropriated the land. This use was equally open to the claimant as a private owner and he was entitled to market value based on such a use. In determining the market value, the Board said at p. 379: "Section 14(4)(a) of the Expropriation Act was put forward as a prohibition to the Board giving consideration to this method of valuation in these circumstances. In the more recent case of McPhail's Equipment Company Limited v. City of Surrey (1995), 57 L.C.R. 57, the British Columbia Expropriation Compensation Board said that, in determining market value, factors to be considered included the suitability of the materials for use as fill or otherwise, accessibility to alternative markets for materials and the expropriating authority's availability as a potential purchaser of the materials. The Board considered that the only value to the claimant of the materials lay in the possible purchase by the expropriating authority. The Board said at p. 76 that: "... (t)he present case varies from those discussed above in that, in those other cases, it was to acquire the particular attributes of the lands (fresh water, rock, gravel) that the authorities expropriated them, whereas in this instance, it was to gain access to the competitive cover material that the respondent took a portion of the claimant's lands. Whereas the authority's intended use of those other lands gave value to them which they would not otherwise have possessed, in this case the respondent's use of the expropriated portion to access Woodin's pit had the effect of rendering essentially worthless the materials on the CNR lands which, prior to expropriation, already had potential value by way of sale to the respondent. (Emphasis added). In other words, the valuation is to be based upon what the parties as willing buyers and sellers would have prudently done, had there been no power of expropriation. "...On the contrary, the Board concludes that, but for the respondent's exercise of its power of expropriation, the respondent would likely have been forced to reach some financial accommodation with the claimant to obtain either the desired access to Woodin's pit or the claimant's own materials. The possibility that the respondent would not have entered into a contract with the claimant but would have pursued other options instead constitutes, in the Board's opinion, an element of risk that figures in the final valuation of the claim. However, the Board is persuaded that, considering both the political and economic costs to the respondent of pursuing those alternatives, that risk was not high. The decisions in the Indian case, Fraser and Agnew, are persuasive against any view that an owner, to found a claim for reduction in value to the remaining land, must have been in the business of actively exploiting its potential for financial gain prior to expropriation." The expropriation may well create an immediate market. For that reason, the Court has said the authority must pay the current market price for the amount of aggregate acquired for use in the project. The holding period or absorption rate of the aggregate tends to be rather longer if one excludes consideration of the public project or the immediacy of the need that has been created. It is clear, however, from these cases that it is proper to consider the imminence of the public project in determining the existence of the market. Otherwise, the authority gets a "free ride" insofar as the compensation on discounted cash flow principles allows the authority to finance the acquisition over a substantial period of time while enjoying the immediate use of the aggregate.
REFERENCES:
|
||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||||
This article is published in the OEA Newsletter, Spring 2002. |
HOME PAGE | ARTICLE MENU | PREVIOUS ARTICLE | NEXT ARTICLE | ||